|
|
Best
if printed in landscape.
Perfect and Imperfect
Competition
Economic theory
often describes an industry as either experiencing perfect competition
or one of several forms of imperfect competition. Production agriculture
is frequently used as an example of an industry with perfect competition;
that is, "your wheat can substitute for my wheat."
Although this may be accurate for many segments of production agriculture,
a question is whether this is changing. Will production agriculture
transform into an industry of less-than-perfect competition? This
page presents a brief overview of perfect competition. With this
background, we can consider whether the perfectly competitive nature of
production agriculture may be changing.
Characteristics
of Perfect Competition
The following list summarizes the characteristics of a perfectly competitive market:
- homogenous
product (one seller's product can easily be substituted with or replaced by the another seller's product),
- many
buyers and sellers (buyers can easily find replacement sellers and sellers can generally find replacement buyers),
- full
(readily available) information (about market opportunities and production
technology),
- easy
entrance and exit (i.e., easy to start or discontinue a business in
the industry), and
- mobile
resources (easy to move resources from this industry to an alternative
use).
As a result of perfect competition, sellers have limited opportunity to earn an economic profit.
- Conversely, an industry that lacks one or more characteristics of perfect competition is considered to be facing imperfect competition and an opportunity to earn more than a minimal return.
- Does this imply that a business person should intentionally try to "eliminate" one or more characteristics of perfect competition so the business now has an opportunity to increase its earnings?
If production
agriculture lacks one of these characteristics, which one is it and why?
As
a result of perfect competition, no one person or business can control
price; there is no nonprice competition (e.g., advertising your product
does not make a difference; the primary factor influencing who the purchaser
is willing to buy from is the price the seller is requesting); and there
is limited opportunity for economic profit.
- However,
some sectors of the food industry lack one or more characteristics of
perfect competition (i.e., they are experiencing imperfect competition)
and this offers those businesses an opportunity to earn economic profits.
- Production agriculture generally lacks mobile resources; that is, it can be difficult to find an alternative use for farmland or for a tractor that is no longer needed to produce ag commodities.
- One would assume, as mentioned above, that lacking a characteristic of perfect competition opens an opportunity for the firms to act as if they are facing imperfect competition, which generally means opportunity to earn more than normal profit. However, in the case of production agriculture, lack of alternative uses for farmland, for example, can have the opposite affect. That is, lacking an alternative use, farmers will continue to use the land to produce ag commodities even if there is already excess production and declining market price for the commodities produced on the land. Therefore in the case of production agriculture, lack of alternative use can lead to a situation of continued downward pressure on commodity prices and business profit.
- What is the impact when individuals are willing to farm either though the business is generating less than a minimal level of income? Is that an example of an immobile "labor" resource? How might that "immobility" impact the overall production agriculture sector?
- It is not uncommon to hear the suggestion that agriculture lacks "easy entrance and exit". A word of caution. Do not interpret this characteristic as if it is asking "how easy is to to initiate a profitable farm business". Instead, ask how easy is it for persons to begin producing agricultural commodities? To answer this last question, begin by considering how easy it is for persons to plant a garden.
- Compare the ease with which individuals can plant a garden to the ease with which individuals could manufacture an airplane. Which industry, in this simple example, is easier to enter: growing food (even if it is only a small quantity) versus building a machine that flies?
- Production agriculture often is not earning an economic profit because others can begin producing food if production agriculture generates an economic profit.
Factors
that influence the level of competition:
- information technology
increases the availability of information; e.g., market information
for sellers and buyers, and information about production techniques.
- access
to new production technology, whether the firm is raising livestock,
baking bread, or transporting oranges. Is the new technology available to
all businesses, or is the technology controlled and accessible to only
some of the businesses?
- advancing
transportation technology (as well as processing, storage, packaging, and other technologies) allows businesses to move products around
the world thereby increasing the number of buyers and sellers in a
market.
An implication
of increasing competition is "reduced opportunities for profit from traditional
sources" (this restates the thought that "firms in perfect competition
have limited opportunity to earn an economic profit").
Competition
among suppliers never hurts consumers.
Intentionally Eliminate One of the Characteristics of Perfect Competition?
In
response, businesses try to identify and shift to markets that offer opportunities
to earn additional profit. These markets are generally less than
perfectly competitive -- these markets lack one or more of the characteristics
of perfect competition listed above. For example, businesses try
to differentiate
their product ("Angus beef"), or reduce the ease of entry (must
have a contract before you can sell), or develop and maintain trade/business
secrets (biotechnology or consumer tastes and preferences).
Businesses
try to move to less-than-perfect competition by being innovative (using
information before it is general knowledge), collectively marketing to
reduce the number of sellers, urging social policies that subsidize or
protect market prices, differentiating their product or service by accepting
added risk in exchange for a premium, or differentiating their product
or service so they are not selling a "commodity."
How do
these thoughts about perfect competition relate to the readings discussed
as part of Trends in Agriculture?
Bottom line -- what basic strategy might agriculture producers want to consider if they find their business is facing perfect competition?
Last Updated
September 20, 2010
|